ECONOMICS OF EDUCATION REVISITED – NEW INSIGHTS FROM IDENTITY AND BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS
Abstract
This paper reviews the economic literature on education along with the attempts to integrate sociological and psychological views of education into standard economic models. The analysis points to the key concepts from sociology and behavioral economics that are translated into inputs to economic models of education, in order to improve the understanding of the economists’ fundamental concern – resource allocation. By extending economic models that capture the relation between investing efforts and expected returns to education, insights from identity economics and behavioral economics shed light to the following question: when and under what circumstances are investments in education effective? Identity economics implies that educational efforts are not perfect determinants of the economic returns to education, taking into account that investments in education are determined by students’ social norms, ideals and identities. Behavioral economics focuses on behavioral biases that affect the individuals’ decisions on investing efforts in education and consequently, their long-term welfare. This novel framework contributes to education research by specifying policy interventions that could mitigate identified behavioral barriers that constrain decision making concerning educational pathways.
Keywords
Full Text:
PDFReferences
Akerlof, G., & Kranton., R. (2000). Economics and Identity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115 (3): 715–53. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355300554881
Akerlof, G., & Kranton., R. (2002). Identity and Schooling: Some Lessons for the Economics of Education. Journal of Economic Literature, 40 (4): 1167–1201. https://doi.org/10.1257/002205102762203585
Akerlof, G., & Kranton., R. (2005). Identity and the Economics of Organizations. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19 (1): 9–32. https://doi.org/10.1257/0895330053147930
Akerlof G., & Kranton R., (2008). Identity, supervision, and work groups, “American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings” 2008, 98(2), pp. 212-217.
Akerlof G., & Kranton R. (2010). Identity Economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press. https://doi.org/10.1515/9781400834181
Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1998). Endogenous Growth Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Arcidiacono, P., Bayer, P., & Hizmo, A. (2010). Beyond signaling and human capital: education and the revelation of ability. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2(4), 76–104. https://doi.org/10.1257/app.2.4.76
Ariely, D. (2009). Predictably irrational: the hidden forces that shape our decisions. New York: Harper Collins.
Austen-Smith, D., & Fryer, R. G. (2005). An Economic Analysis of “Acting White”. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(2), 551–583. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/120.2.551
Avery, C., & Kane, T. (2004). Student perceptions of college opportunities: The Boston COACH program. In C. M. Hoxby (Ed.). College choices: the economics of where to go, when to go, and how to pay for it, (pp. 355–394). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. https://doi.org/10.7208/chicago/9780226355375.003.0009
Barro, R. (1991). Economic growth in a cross section of countries. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106 (2), 407-443. https://doi.org/10.2307/2937943
Barro, R. (1997). Determinants of Economic Growth. A cross-country Empirical Study (NBER Working Paper No. 5698). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w5698
Bauman, Z. (2000). Liquid Modernity. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Beck, U. (2000). Risk Society – Towards a New Modernity. Sage Publications Ltd.
Becker, G. (1964). Human Capital. Chicago: Chicago University Press.
Bénabou, R., & Tirole, J. (2002). Self-confidence and personal motivation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3), 871–915. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355302760193913
Bénabou, R., & Tirole, J. (2011). Identity, Morals, and Taboos: Beliefs as Assets. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126 (2): 805–55. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjr002
Benartzi, S., & Thaler, R. (2000). Myopic loss aversion and the equity premium puzzle. In D. Kahneman & A. Tversky (Eds.), Choices, values, and frames (pp. 301-316). Cambridge, UK, and New York: Cambridge University Press and Russell Sage Foundation.
Benartzi, S., & Thaler, R. (2007). Heuristics and biases in retirement savings behavior. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(3), 81–104. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.21.3.81
Benhassine, N., Devoto, F., Duflo, E., Dupas, P., & Pouliquen, V. (2015). Turning a shove into a nudge? A “labelled cash transfer” for education. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 7(3), 86–125. https://doi.org/10.1257/pol.20130225
Bhuller, M., Mogstad, M., & Salvanes, K. (2017). Life cycle earnings, education premiums and internal rates of return. Journal of Labor Economics, 35(4), 993–1030. https://doi.org/10.1086/692509
Bridgeland, J., DiIulio, J., & Burke Morison, K. (2006). The silent epidemic: Perspectives of high school dropouts. Technical report, Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation.
Cadena, B., & Keys, B. (2015). Human capital and lifetime costs of impatience. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 7(3), 126–156. https://doi.org/10.1257/pol.20130081
Camerer, C., & Loewenstein, G. (2004). Behavioral economics: Past, present, future. In C. Camerer, G. Loewenstein, & M. Rabin (Eds.), Advances in behavioral economics (pp. 3-51). New York and Princeton, NJ: Russell Sage Foundation and Princeton University.
Card, D., & Krueger. B. (1992). Does School Quality Matter? Returns to Education and the Characteristics of Public Schools in the United States. Journal of Political Economy, 100 (1), 1-40. https://doi.org/10.1086/261805
Carrell, S., Fullerton, R., & West, J. (2009). Does your cohort matter? Measuring peer effects in college achievement. Journal of Labor Economics, 27(3), 439–464. https://doi.org/10.1086/600143
Chande, R., Luca, M., Sanders, M., Soon, X., Borcan, O., Barak-Corren, N., et al. (2015). Curbing adult student attrition: Evidence from a field experiment. Harvard Business School Working Paper 15-065. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2563757
Chen, S., & Schildberg-Hörisch, H. (2018). Looking at the bright side: The motivational effect of overconfidence. (Discussion Paper No 291). Düsseldorf: Düsseldorf University Press.
Chetty, R., Friedman, J., & Rockoff, J. (2014). Measuring the impacts of teachers II: Teacher value-added and student outcomes in adulthood. American Economic Review, 104(9), 2633–2679. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.9.2633
Contreras, D., Elacqua, G., Martinez, M., & Miranda, A. (2016). Bullying, identity and school performance: Evidence from Chile. International Journal of Educational Development, 51, 147-162. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijedudev.2016.09.004
Damgaard, M., & Nielsen, H. (2018) Nudging in education. Economics of Education Review, 64, 313-342. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econedurev.2018.03.008
DellaVigna, S. (2009). Psychology and economics: evidence from the field. Journal of Economic Literature, 47(2), 315–372. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.47.2.315
De Paola, M., & Scoppa, V. (2015). Procrastination, academic success and the effectiveness of a remedial program. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 115, 217–236. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2014.12.007
Eckstein, Z., Wolpin, K. (1999). Why youths drop out of high school: the impact of preferences, opportunities and abilities. Econometrica 67 (6), 1295–1339. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0262.00081
Evans, B., Baker, R., & Dee, T. (2016). Persistence patterns in massive open online courses (MOOCs). Journal of Higher Education, 87(2), 206–242. https://doi.org/10.1080/00221546.2016.11777400
Filippin, A., Paccagnella, M. (2012). Family background, self-confidence and economic outcomes. Economics of Education Review, 31(5), 824–834. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econedurev.2012.06.002
Fisher, I. (1906). The Nature of Capital and Income. New York: Macmillan.
Fryer, R. (2016). Information, non-financial incentives, and student achievement: Evidence from a text messaging experiment. Journal of Public Economics, 144, 109–121. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2016.10.009
Giddens, A. (1991). Modernity and Self-Identity: Self in the Late Modern Age. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Golsteyn, B., Grönqvist, H. & Lindahl, L., (2014). Adolescent time preferences predict lifetime outcomes. The Economic Journal, 124, 739-761. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecoj.12095
Hastings, J., Van Weelden, R., & Weinstein, J. (2007). Preferences, information, and parental choice behavior in public school choice (NBER Working Paper No. 12995). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w12995
Heckman, J., Lochner, L., & Todd, P. (2006). Earnings functions, rates of return, and treatment effects: The Mincer equation and beyond. In E. Hanushek, & F. Welch (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Education (pp. 307–458). Elsevier B.V. https://doi.org/10.1016/s1574-0692(06)01007-5
Heckman, J., & Kautz, T. (2012). Hard evidence on soft skills. Labor Economics, 19 (4), 451–464. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.labeco.2012.05.014
Hoxby, C. (2000). The Effects of Class Size on Student Achievement: New Evidence from Population Variation, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115:4, 1239-85. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355300555060
Hoxby, C., & Turner, S. (2015). What high-achieving low-income students know about college. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 105(5), 514–517. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.p20151027
Jabbar, H. (2011). The behavioral economics of education: New directions for research. Educational Researcher, 40(9), 446–453. https://doi.org/10.3102/0013189x11426351
Jackson, C., Rockoff, J., & Staiger, D. (2014). Teacher effects and teacher-related policies. Annual Review of Economics, 6(1), 801–825. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-080213-040845
Johnson, H. (1960). The Political Economy of Opulence. Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, 26 (4), 552-564. https://doi.org/10.2307/138933
Johnson, E., & Goldstein, D. (2003). Do defaults save lives? Science, 302(5649), 1338–1339. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1091721
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263-291. https://doi.org/10.2307/1914185
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J., & Thaler, R. (1991). Anomalies: The endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1), 193–206. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.5.1.193
Kiker, B. (1966). The Historical Roots of the Concept of Human Capital. Journal of Political Economy, 74 (5), 481-499. https://doi.org/10.1086/259201
Koch, A., Nafciger, J., & Nielsen H. (2015) Behavioral economics of education. Journal of Economic Behaviour & Organization, 115, 3-17. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2014.09.005
Kranton, R. (2016). Identity Economics 2016: Where Do Social Distinctions and Norms Come From? American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 106 (5), 405–409. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.p20161038
Krueger, A., & Lindahl, M. (2001). Education for growth: Why and for whom? Journal of Economic Literature, 39 (4), 1101-1136. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.39.4.1101
Laibson, D., (1997). Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112 (2), 443–477. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355397555253
Lavecchia, A., Liu, H., & Oreopoulos, P. (2016). Behavioral economics of education: Progress and possibilities. In E. Hanushek, S. Machin, & L. Woessmann (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of education (pp. 1–74). Elsevier, B. V. https://doi.org/10.1016/b978-0-444-63459-7.00001-4
Levitt, S., List, J., Neckermann, S., & Sadoff, S. (2016). The behaviouralist goes to school: Leveraging behavioral economics to improve economic performance. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 4(8), 183–219. https://doi.org/10.1257/pol.20130358
Lochner, L. (2011). Nonproductive benefits of education: crime, health, and good citizenship. In E. Hanushek, & F. Welch (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Education (pp. 183–282). Elsevier B.V. https://doi.org/10.3386/w16722
Lucas, R. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22 (1), 3-42. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(88)90168-7
Mankiw, N., Romer, D., & Weil, D. (1992). A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107 (2), 407-437. https://doi.org/10.2307/2118477
Mincer, J. (1958). Investment in human capital and personal income distribution. Journal of Political Economy, 66(4), 281–302. https://doi.org/10.1086/258055
Oreopoulos, P. (2007). Do dropouts drop out too soon? Wealth, health and happiness from compulsory schooling. Journal of Public Economics, 97(11-12), 2213–2229. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.02.002
Oreopoulos, P., & Dunn, R. (2013). Information and college access: Evidence from a randomized field experiment. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 115(1), 3–26. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9442.2012.01742.x
Oreopoulos, P., & Ford, R. (2016). Keeping college options open: A field experiment to help all high school seniors through the college application process. (NBER Working Paper No. 22320). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w22320
Page, L., Garboua, L., & Montmarquette, C. (2007). Aspiration levels and educational choices: An experimental study. Economics of Education Review, 26(6), 747–757. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econedurev.2007.06.001
Reyes, M., Brackett, M., Rivers, S., White, M., & Salovey, P. (2012). Classroom emotional climate, student engagement, and academic achievement. Journal of Educational Psychology, 104(3), 700-712. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0027268
Rogers, T., & Feller, A. (2016). Discouraged by peer excellence: Exposure to exemplary peer performance causes quitting. Psychological Science, 27(3), 365–374. https://doi.org/10.1177/0956797615623770
Schultz, T. (1960). Capital Formation by Education. Journal of Political Economy, 68 (6), 571-583. https://doi.org/10.1086/258393
Schultz, T. (1961). Investment in Human Capital. The American Economic Review, 51 (1), 1-17.
Solow, R. (1956). A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70 (1), 65–94. https://doi.org/10.2307/1884513
Steel, P. (2007). The nature of procrastination: a meta-analytic and theoretical review of quintessential self-regulatory failure. Psychological Bulletin, 133 (1), 65-94. https://doi.org/10.1037/0033-2909.133.1.65
Tan, E. (2014). Human Capital Theory: A Holistic Criticism. Review of Educational Research, 84 (3), 411-445. https://doi.org/10.3102/0034654314532696
Thaler, R., & Benartzi, S. (2004). Save more tomorrow: Using behavioral economics to increase employee saving. Journal of Political Economy, 112(1), 164–187. https://doi.org/10.1086/380085
Thaler, R., & Sunstein, C. (2008). Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth and Happiness. Yale University Press.
von Thunen, H. (1875). Der Isolierte Staat. Chicago: Comparative Education Center, University of Chicago. https://doi.org/10.5962/bhl.title.24798
Todd, P., Wolpin, K. (2003). On the specification and estimation of the production function for cognitive achievement. Economic Journal, 113, 3–33. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0297.00097
Walton, G., & Cohen, G. (2011). A brief social-belonging intervention improves academic and health outcomes of minority students. Science, 1447–4151. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1198364
Yeager, D., Romero, C., Paunesku, D., Hulleman, C., Schneider, B., Hinojosa, C., et al. (2016). Using design thinking to improve psychological interventions: The case of the growth mindset during the transition to high school. Journal of Educational Psychology, 108(3), 374–391. https://doi.org/10.1037/edu0000098
Refbacks
- There are currently no refbacks.
© University of Niš, Serbia
Creative Commons licence CC BY-NC-ND
Print ISSN: 0353-7919
Online ISSN: 1820-7804